Notes


1. CAPM

  • Market Portfolio: The portfolio of risky assets with the Maximum Sharpe Ratio (Best Allocation of weights of risky assets in the investable universe, excluding the risk-free asset such that you get the highest historical Sharpe Ratio \(\Big[\frac{\mathbb{E}[r_{\text{portfolio}}]=w^\top \mu}{\sigma_{\text{portfolio}}}\Big]\))

    • We get this by running mean-variance optimization for universe of risky assetsusing historical returns

  • Key takeaway:

For any security \(i\):

\begin{aligned} \mathbb{E}[r_i] &= \beta_i\underbrace{(\mathbb{E}[r_{\text{Market Portfolio}}] - r_f)}_{\text{Market Portfolio’s Expected Excess Return}} + r_f \end{aligned}


2. APT

  • Multi-factor version of CAPM: Instead of assuming that Stock returns are only affected by market exposure, we find other factor exposures

    • Fama-French 4 factor model proposes 3 other factors that stock returns are exposed to

    • We can create other factors by ourselves such that our portfolio is only exposed to that factor (weather)


3. Black-Litterman

  • Bayesian Framework of updating Portfolio weights given active views: Use Active Views to update the Prior expected return of portfolio to get posterior.


4. Futures

  • Futures contract price $\( will always \)=$ Actual spot price when futures contract matures

  • Current Spot Price \(S_{0}\): How much the asset is selling for right now (\(t = 0\)) with information from \(t \leq 0\)

  • Current Futures Contract Price \(F_{0,T}\): How much the market thinks (\(t = 0\)) the asset will sell for with information from \(t \leq 0\)

Current Spot Price \(S_{0}\) Vs. Actual Current Futures Contract Price \(F_{0,T}\)

  1. Intangible Asset Model (Stocks): Link between Current Spot Price \(S_{0}\) & Theoretical Current Futures Contract Price \(\hat{F_{0,T}}\)

\begin{aligned} \hat{F_{0,T}} &= S_0 e^{r_fT} \ r_f &= \text{Risk-free rate / Interest Rate} \ \end{aligned}

  1. Cost of Carry Model (Commodities): Link between Current Spot Price \(S_{0}\) & Theoretical Current Futures Contract Price \(\hat{F_{0,T}}\)

\begin{aligned} \hat{F_{0, T}} &= S_{0} e^{(r_f + u - q - y)T} \ r_f &= \text{Risk-free rate / Interest Rate} \ u &= \text{Cost of Storage} \ q &= \text{Dividends / Cash Benefit from holding the asset} \ y &= \text{Convienience Yield} \ \end{aligned}

Comparing \(S_{0}\) and \(F_{0,T}\) is seeing whether costs outweigh the benefits of buying the asset right now:

  1. Contango: \(S_{0} < F_{0,T}\)

    • The market thinks that the costs of holding the asset over period \(T\) > the benefits

    • We can justify this theoretically as \(r + u > c + y\) means cost > the benfits of holding the asset over period \(T\) which will make \(S_{0} < \hat{F_{0,T}}\)

  2. Backwardation: \(S_{0} > F_{0,T}\)

    • The market thinks that the costs of holding the asset over period \(T\) < the benefits

    • We can justify this theoretically as \(r + u < c + y\) means cost < the benfits of holding the asset over period \(T\) which will make \(S_{0} > \hat{F_{0,T}}\)

Expected Future Spot Price \(\mathbb{E}[S_T]\) Vs. Current Futures Contract Price \(F_{0,T}\)

Link between Expected Future Spot Price \(\mathbb{E}[S_T]\) & Current Spot Price \(S_{0}\)

\begin{aligned} \mathbb{E}[S_T] &= S_{0} e^{k_eT} \ k_e &= \mathbb{E}[R_{stock}], \text{ The Discount Rate / Expected Return of the stock via CAPM} \ \end{aligned}

Link between Expected Future Spot Price \(\mathbb{E}[S_T]\) & Theoretical Current Futures Contract Price \(\hat{F_{0,T}}\)

\begin{aligned} \hat{F_{0,T}} &= \mathbb{E}[S_T] e^{(r_f-k_e)T} \ r_f &= \text{Risk-free rate / Interest Rate} \ k_e &= \mathbb{E}[R_{stock}], \text{ The Discount Rate / Expected Return of the stock via CAPM} \ \end{aligned}

Comparing \(\mathbb{E}[S_T]\) and \(F_{0,T}\) is seeing how much the longer of the futures contract is compensated for the equity risk premium (\(\mathbb{E}[R_{stock}] - r_f\)):

  1. Normal Contango: \(\mathbb{E}[S_T] < F_{0,T}\)

    • Less common, market thinks that equity return is < than the risk-free rate

    • We can justify this theoretically as \(\mathbb{E}[S_T] < F_{0,T}\) happens when \(r_f > k_e\)

  2. Normal Backwardation: \(\mathbb{E}[S_T] > F_{0,T}\)

    • More common, market thinks that equity return is > than the risk-free rate

    • We can justify this theoretically as \(\mathbb{E}[S_T] > F_{0,T}\) happens when \(r_f < k_e\)

    • In this case, longer of futures contract pays a price \(F_{0,T}\) and is expected to receive the asset of price \(\mathbb{E}[S_T]\) at maturity - the expected profit of \(\mathbb{E}[S_T] - F_{0,T}\) is compensation for the equity risk premium and the hedger is willing to pay for this in order to lock in the price and limit the losses.


5. Carry


6. Risk-parity / Risk-budgetting

  • We start off after finding a set of assets that we want to long on

  • We place the \(w > 0\) constraint in the risk-budgetting optimization because it cannot be \(w = 0\) because we already know we want to long it, and it cannot \(w \leq 0\) because we want to long it.

  • Risk-parity means \(b = \frac{1}{n}\mathbf{1}\), all risks allocated to each opportunity is equal, risk parity is a special case of risk-budgetting

  • No one can make a good argument on why you don’t want to allocate equal risk to each opportunity


7. Active Management

Fundamental Law of Active Management (Bets must be INDEPENDENT):

\begin{aligned} IR &= IC \sqrt{BR}, \ IC &= 2\text{Accuracy} - 1 \ \end{aligned}

  • HFT’s secret sauce is making so many bets such that their accuracy only needs to be very low because the BR bumps up their IR

  • Fundamental investors need to have a very high accuracy in order to get the same IR as HFTs

  • Quants exist between HFT and Fundamental, higher bets than fundamentals, lower bets than HFT, higher accuracy than HFT, lower accuracy than Fundamental